Don’t miss the latest developments in business and finance.

<b>Justin Wolfers:</b> Why Angus Deaton deserved the economics Nobel

Perhaps his most important effect has been within the field of development economics, which focuses on the economies of poor countries

Image
Justin Wolfers
Last Updated : Oct 13 2015 | 10:28 PM IST
The central contribution of Angus Deaton, the latest winner of the Nobel Memorial Prize in economics, has been to shift the gaze of his fellow economists beyond measures of income to broader measures of well-being.

Much of his research has focused on consumption - measures of the food people eat, the condition of their housing, and the services they consume. And he has been a trailblazer in shifting the attention of economists away from the behaviour of economywide aggregates such as gross domestic product, and towards the analysis of individual households.

This is also the first Nobel to acknowledge explicitly the increasingly empirical nature of modern economic research. There are probably more such Nobels to come.

Yet for all the power that modern statistics brings, Deaton has argued forcefully that it is neither a panacea nor a substitute for economic theory.

He has been an influential counterweight against a popular strand of econometric practice arguing that if you want to know whether something works, you should just test it, preferably with a randomised control trial. In Deaton's telling, the observation that a particular government intervention worked is no guarantee that it will work again, or in another context.

He has brought microeconomics - traditionally a field populated by theorists - into closer connection with the data. Partly because of his influence, modern microeconomists are more likely to spend their days knee-deep in large-scale data sets describing the real-world decisions made by millions of people, and less likely to be mired in Greek-letter abstractions.

Much of the empirical revolution in economics has been enabled by the tools that Deaton developed. These tools reimagine the role of economic theory, using it to organise and interpret the tidal wave of data coming from the hundreds of household surveys conducted around the world each year.

This focus on empirics has been a boon for the field of econometrics, which is the application of statistical methods to economic problems. Deaton's signature achievement in this area has been in forcing empirical researchers to pay closer attention to questions of measurement. For too long, econometric analysis had proceeded as if data were simply handed down from a statistician-loving higher power. The reality is far uglier: Data are imperfect, surveys can be unrepresentative, people misreport, and attempts to recontact survey participants often fail. Deaton confronts these issues head-on, and he has taught economists how to extract meaning from imperfect data.

More than any other economist I know, he understands that to get the big picture right, you've got to get all the small details right, too.

This is a lesson that I learned firsthand, as my co-author (and significant other) Betsey Stevenson and I were puzzling over some data that appeared to show that people in certain low-income countries nonetheless reported high levels of life satisfaction. Deaton, who was equally perplexed, suggested that we dig a little deeper, as he recalled that some of the surveys were not representative samples of the entire population. Sure enough, several weeks of digging through the archives and sifting through the appendices to old codebooks revealed Deaton to be correct, and those puzzling observations to be simply the result of pollsters surveying only richer (and therefore probably happier) people in those poor countries. These statistical anomalies had partly hidden the strong link between life satisfaction and average incomes.

Deaton has also made important contributions to macroeconomics. This distinction between individual and aggregate behaviour is particularly important to the study of consumption. While macroeconomists had been satisfied that their theories could explain the relationship between the total level of consumption and total income in the economy, Deaton showed that those same theories struggled to explain what individual households were doing.

But perhaps Deaton's most important effect has been within the field of development economics, which focuses on the economies of poor countries. This is a research programme born of deep personal conviction. As he recently wrote, "Those of us who were lucky enough to be born in the right countries have a moral obligation to reduce poverty and ill health in the world."

A generation ago, development economics was a field populated by 'country doctors' - globe-trotting macroeconomists willing to make house calls to any country willing to provide them with a first-class ticket, so that they could proffer their preferred prescription, be it a more muscular industrial policy, a big push of infrastructure development, increased national savings or a faster shift to a market economy. The countries varied, but the prescriptions rarely did.

Today, development economics is a far more interesting and nuanced field, with practitioners focused on understanding the lives of the poor, and in uncovering the subtle ways in which immature economic institutions hinder their development. Rather than studying a few dozen countries, modern development economists are likely to pore over data describing the economic lives of thousands of families within each country. And much of that data comes from his decades-long collaboration with the World Bank, as his work has inspired much of its recent work on measuring and assessing poverty. The result is a sharper picture of the incidence and causes of global poverty.

More recently, Deaton has turned his attention to measures of subjective well-being, including happiness. In his 2010 presidential address to the American Economic Association, Deaton highlighted the problems in constructing coherent measures of global poverty. Measures of income don't offer much insight unless they can be thought of in terms of differences in purchasing power. But it is impossible to assess who has more or less purchasing power when people in different countries face different prices and choose to buy different goods. Given this problem, Deaton makes the radical suggestion that economists just ask people about their well-being instead.

More than that, he's motivated by the questions that really matter, he is intellectually relentless, he has enormous integrity and he has devoted his life to understanding and improving the lot of the poor. He's the perfect role model for any young economist.

(The author is a professor of economics and public policy at the University of Michigan)
© 2015 The New York Times News Service

More From This Section

Disclaimer: These are personal views of the writer. They do not necessarily reflect the opinion of www.business-standard.com or the Business Standard newspaper

First Published: Oct 13 2015 | 9:44 PM IST

Next Story