Don’t miss the latest developments in business and finance.

Money mischief

Reforming labour markets would be a better use of Narendra Modi's political capital than justifying the note ban

Demonetisation, Note ban. Illustration by Binay Sinha
Demonetisation, Note ban. Illustration by Binay Sinha
Deepak Lal
Last Updated : Nov 28 2017 | 11:17 PM IST
In 1341, Mohammed bin Tughlaq suffered a heavy drain upon the treasury from his munificence in dealing with the distress caused by his decision to move the capital to Daulatabad and back again, as the new capital did not have an adequate water supply. With many perishing on the two forced marches, the sultan opened the fisc to mitigate the distress of his subjects. To meet this fiscal drain, the sultan made his famous experiment of instituting a token currency of brass and copper to replace the silver and gold coinage. But he forgot that the success of this scheme depended upon a state monopoly in issuing the token currency. The result says contemporary political thinker Ziauddin Barani “turned the house of every Hindu into a mint, and the Hindus of the various provinces coined crores and lakhs of copper coins”. Their value relative to the silver-gold old currency soon fell so low “that they were not valued more than pebbles or potsherds”. With the ensuing disruption of trade “the sultan repealed his edict, and in great wrath he proclaimed that whoever possessed copper coins should bring them to the treasury and receive the old ones in exchange…. So many of these copper tankas were brought to the treasury that heaps of them rose up in Tughlakabad like mountains.” How this run on its reserves was met is unexplained, but as the 19th century expert on Indian numismatics E Thomas pointed out “if good money was paid for every token, true or forged, the sultan’s temporary loan from his own subjects must have been repaid with more than even oriental rates of interest” (Stanley Lane-Poole: Mediaeval India, pp. 135-136). This was the first conspicuous Indian example of what Milton Friedman described in his book entitled Money Mischief.

On November 8, 2016, Prime Minister Narendra Modi announced the demonetisation of 86 per cent of Indian currency and its replacement by new notes. But the remonetisation, which ideally needed to occur simultaneously to prevent any contraction of output, was dilatory. Given the need for secrecy, the replacement notes could not have been printed and stored domestically before the announcement. After November 8, printing presses at Indian mints were estimated (in an editorial in this newspaper) to take about a year to print the replacement currency. That this was correct, see Figure 1 showing the broad money supply in India from 2010 to 2017. There was a massive monetary contraction in the last three months of 2016 which has not still been fully reversed (on the basis of the annual rate of money growth). 

We know from Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz’s magisterial A Monetary History of the United States that the Great Depression was caused by a massive monetary contraction engineered by the US Fed in the late 1920s, and not by the various ad hoc explanations (including Keynesian ones), which had been advanced, and which have been echoed by many commentators on India’s recent growth slowdown. That broad money movements are relevant in explaining changes in nominal gross domestic product (GDP) was reiterated by Ben Bernanke’s fulfillment of his pledge to Milton Friedman on his deathbed that the Fed had absorbed the lesson of his book with Anna Schwartz and would not allow the US broad money supply to contract. He did this during the Great Recession through adopting quantitative easing (open market operations to raise the broad money supply) which prevented the Great Recession from turning into a Great Depression.

As the editorial in this newspaper also noted, given the constraints on the speedy replacement of notes through domestic mints, India could have used foreign facilities for printing currency. In the mid 1990s, I was a visiting fellow at the International Centre for Economic Research in Turin. My neighbour in an adjoining office was the last governor of the Somali central bank before his country descended into chaos and he was exiled. He showed me a graph of the inflation rate in lawless Somalia. It was flat, he explained, because Somali currency had been securely printed by the Swiss firm De La Rue and shipped by air to Somalia. The last consignment had arrived just before Somalia collapsed and he fled. As there was no government to pay for any further printing and shipping of currency from Switzerland, the Somali money supply remained fixed, and hence there was no inflation!

So we would expect the monetary contraction lasting nearly a year after demonetisation would have led to a sharp contraction in nominal GDP. The Economic Survey 2016-17, Volume 2, in Box 3, notes that instead growth of nominal GDP accelerated with the substantial decline in broad money. They call this is a puzzle. It is not. As the informal sector is primarily cash-dependent, it would have contracted disproportionately more than the organised sector. But, a continuing lacuna in Indian national income accounting is that informal sector output is only reliably surveyed in quinquennial NSS surveys. In the intervening years it is estimated as a fixed proportion of the organised sector. So there is no firm basis for judging the effects of demonetisation on nominal GDP. Moreover, there is no long-term survey data on monthly or quarterly employment in the informal sector to judge the employment effects after demonetisation, which may not be reversible.

The major benefit from demonetisation was claimed to be the extinction of the black economy. As many observers noted it would at best deal with the existing stock of black money but not the flows. There are two major sources of the demand for these flows: elections and construction. The only way to stop the former is to allow transparent and unlimited donations to political parties which are audited. For the second it is to reduce/eliminate stamp duty on real estate transactions which will remove the incentive to avoid it though using black money.

As someone who had welcomed Mr Modi’s election as providing hope that the dirigiste economy of the past with its continuing distortions of the factor markets for land, labour and capital would at last be reformed allowing for rapid labour intensive growth, I remain disappointed. The reforms of the capital markets with the institution of a bankruptcy law and the beginning of tackling the NPA’s of the banking system are welcome. But a complete reversal of Indira Gandhi’s bank nationalisation is needed. Whilst the reforms of the land and labour markets formulated in the early ordinances should now be possible once the NDA has a majority in the Rajya Sabha. The labour market reforms will require taking on the “insiders” in the organised sector. This would be a better use of the PM’s political capital than the own goal of demonetisation, whose most recent changing aim is said to be a cashless economy — the subject of a future column.

Illustration by Binay Sinha


More From This Section

Disclaimer: These are personal views of the writer. They do not necessarily reflect the opinion of www.business-standard.com or the Business Standard newspaper
Next Story