Don’t miss the latest developments in business and finance.

Sukumar Mukhopadhyay: Giving a dog a bad name

Image
Sukumar Mukhopadhyay New Delhi
Last Updated : Jun 14 2013 | 6:07 PM IST
SEZs can be attacked for several things such as forcible land acquisition, but the indirect tax benefits to them flow from the concept of zero-rating for all exports.
 
Many economic analysts continue to have certain misconceptions with respect to the indirect tax aspect of SEZs. The first point that needs to be made is that nothing should be condemned for wrong reasons. SEZs should be judged in the same way you would many other export promotion schemes such as Drawback, Duty Entitlement Pass Book (DEPB) and Export Promotion Capital Goods (EPCG) while discussing indirect taxes.
 
All these schemes have a common feature: all envisage a zero-rating of the goods exported. This means not only that the final product exported is exempted from customs duty, excise duty, service tax, and so on, but that even the inputs are not taxable. It does not make a difference whether the products exported are being made in SEZs or in other schemes that are outside the SEZ. The reason why SEZs have become such a burning issue now is because they entail land acquisition which often is forcible. That is not an indirect tax matter.
 
The first misconception is the notion that revenue forgone in the course of export is actually a loss of revenue due to export (that is, cost of export). Economic analysts variously refer to revenue foregone as "cost to revenue" or "loss of revenue" or "cost of export". Actually, the revenue foregone is not a loss of revenue at all, neither is it a cost of export. The accepted principle all over the world is to export the goods and not to export the duty. Foregoing of duty is necessary to make export possible. If exemptions and remissions of duty were not given, hardly any exports would be possible. All countries resort to zero-rating, which the WTO permits. 
 
REVENUE FOREGONE ON ACCOUNT OF EXPORT PROMOTION CONCESSIONS
(Rs. in crores)
Name of the Scheme2005-06
(Provisional)
2006-07
(Estimated)
Advance Licence Scheme13,36117,610
EOU/EHTP/STP10,27713,651
EPCG5,3328,648
DEPB Scheme5,6504,873
SEZ1,0702,146
DFRC815824
Duty Free Import 
Authorisation Scheme

""

530
DFCEC Scheme5851,266
Target Plus Scheme5003,120
Vishesh Krishi and Gram Udyog Yojana60800
Served from Indian Scheme 40300
Total37,59053,768
 
If India does not do it, Indian goods will simply be priced out. So there will be no production for export, and only goods meant for the domestic market will be produced. But if these goods were not going to be produced, there would be no duty collection either. In which case, where is the loss? An example will clarify things. Let us say, Honda manufactures 120 motorcycles in India. They sell 100 in the Indian market and export 20. If there is no zero-rating for these 20 motorcycles, they will be priced out in the world market and there will be no export of these motorcycles. So Honda will only manufacture 100 and not the extra 20. For these 20 which are not manufactured, there will obviously be no customs duty paid for any parts or paints that would not be imported. Also there will be no central excise duty paid as there will be no manufacture. So the question of duty foregone will not arise. There would be no collection of duty if these 20 are not exported. If these 20 are exported and zero-rated, no duties will be collected either. Both situations are the same. So one cannot say that the duty foregone due to exports is a loss of tax. The figure of revenue foregone shown in Table 8 at page 36 of the Expenditure Budget of 2007-08, reproduced here, is relevant only statistically. The statistical relevance of the figures of duty foregone is only to see how much duty has been refunded or has not been charged. Such figures are necessary only for formulating the Budget and for various analyses in the ministry of finance.
 
The second misconception is that the indirect tax concessions to SEZs are enormous. I have seen several writings and attended seminars on SEZs where speakers, economists and generalists alike eloquently condemn SEZs on the ground that thousands of crores of indirect taxes such as customs and excise are being lost in the concessions given to SEZs. And they talk nothing about other export promotion schemes at all. As the table shows, the revenue foregone is much more in various other schemes. However, when the SEZs increase in number, the revenue foregone will be more. But the point remains that there is revenue foregone is for all the schemes and not for SEZs alone. The only difference is that in SEZs even infrastructure gets indirect tax benefit for materials used, namely steel, cement, paints and so on. This extra benefit for developers cannot be properly calculated.
 
The third point is about what the cost of export really is. It consists of the elements of misuse of all the schemes mentioned above and in SEZs. On the basis of available data, some rough estimates can be made of the actual cost in the past for the other schemes but not for SEZs as no reliable data are available. The misuse mainly arises in cases where exports do not take place but the concessions are availed of.
 
In the case of SEZs, some misuses have been detected of goods being smuggled out into the domestic tariff area without payment of duty or without being exported. But no firm data are available.
 
There is also a subsidy element in the DEPB scheme. The rates of refund of duty in DEPB as compared to Drawback scheme for corresponding goods are far more. In an overall estimate they are even more than double. This shows the element of subsidy. However, studies show that such cost of export due to misuse and subsidy are very little compared to the total duty collected as indirect tax. In the case of SEZs, this question of cost of export due to subsidy does not arise, as there is no availment of DEPB or any other schemes within the SEZ.
 
In conclusion,
  • It is wrong to say that there is a huge concession of indirect taxes in SEZs. The revenue foregone is the same in SEZs as well as in all other schemes outside SEZs;
  • The only extra revenue foregone in SEZs is the one in relation to developers;
  • It is wrong to say that the revenue forgone is the cost of export;
  • The cost of export consists of the misuse of the schemes and the subsidy elements; and
  • SEZs can possibly be faulted for many other reasons such as forcible land acquisition, creating a landlord class, diversion of industries and investment from other places to SEZs, but not for the reason that there is an enormous loss of revenue from indirect taxes and inordinately large cost of export from SEZs.

    smukher2000@yahoo.com

  •  

    Also Read

    Disclaimer: These are personal views of the writer. They do not necessarily reflect the opinion of www.business-standard.com or the Business Standard newspaper

    First Published: Aug 25 2007 | 12:00 AM IST

    Next Story