Business Standard

<b>A V Rajwade:</b> Exchange rate policy - II

The least costly measure to manage exchange rates is to give up the liberal capital account

Image

A V Rajwade New Delhi

The subheading given to my last column (“Our exchange rate policy”, April 26) may have created an impression that it discussed my expectations of what the official policy “could possibly look like”. In fact, the article was, as stated in the first paragraph, my articulation of what the policy should be. I continue.

As argued, an overvalued exchange rate encourages consumption, particularly of imported goods, and is a deflationary factor as far as the domestic economy is concerned; on the other hand, an undervalued exchange rate reduces consumption below the level the productive capacity of the economy can afford, thus militating against the basic objective of growth which is to increase consumption. Both these conclusions assume that there is a “correct” value of the exchange rate which would balance the needs of growth and consumption. In many ways, a carefully constructed Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER) is a reasonable measure of the direction of movement of an exchange rate, and also of its deviation from fair value. (The REER index has some weaknesses but so do all indices used for policy-making — the wholesale price index, the consumer price index, the index for industrial production, etc.) The second measure of the deviation from fair value is the resultant imbalance between the economy’s current external earnings and expenditure.

 

Believers in market efficiency would argue that market prices are self-correcting and that, therefore, the central bank should leave the exchange rate to the market, an argument that is rarely made in relation to the domestic value of money. (No modern democracy, however, can afford to take such a market fundamentalist approach to the value of money.) Arguably, the exchange rate would be self-correcting if the foreign exchange market were to consist primarily of current account transactions — an overvalued domestic currency would make imports cheaper and exports uneconomic, increasing the demand for imports and dollars to pay for them, even as the supply of dollars falls because of the lower export earnings. The resultant demand-supply change in the foreign exchange market would itself correct the exchange rate. The fact is, however, that very often flows other than current account transactions dominate today’s foreign exchange markets. Globally, the volume of exchange transactions is about 30 times the trade flows. Even in the domestic market, the gross amount of transactions is around 14 times the current account transactions.

Capital account flows are often cyclical. For example, capital inflows in the equity market would tend to appreciate both share prices and the exchange rate which, in turn, attract more investors thus continuing the cycle, carrying the exchange rate significantly away from fair value. Opening the capital account for outflows by residents cannot really compensate since, if returns in the domestic market are perceived to be attractive, residents will also prefer to keep the money at home. Many emerging markets have witnessed the cyclical movement of capital flows in the reverse direction also, by both residents and non-residents. Given the well-known herd instinct of investors, the only counter-cyclical force can be the central bank.

It is well accepted that an independent monetary policy, a managed exchange rate and a liberal capital account cannot coexist (“the impossible trinity”). In practice, however, it is possible to manage the exchange rate even in a relatively liberal capital account regime, by intervention in the exchange market and sterilisation of the impact on money supply through open market operations or changes in the reserve ratio of the banking system. It is sometimes argued that sterilisation of the excess money supply can lead to an increase in domestic interest rates, which would be detrimental to growth. This argument, however, has limitations. For one thing, if the currency is allowed to appreciate to avoid intervention and sterilisation, this too is a deflationary factor for the economy. Second, so long as sterilisation is limited to the money created through intervention, it should leave the market liquidity, and hence interest rates, unchanged.

It cannot, however, be gainsaid that if domestic interest rates are higher than the earnings on reserves, sterilisation through open market operations will entail a measurable money cost. On the other hand, if sterilisation is done through increasing the cash reserve requirement, there are no costs to the central bank — or even to the banking system since the central bank is impounding only the money it had created through intervention.

But coming back to the impossible trinity, if capital flows continue to surge as many analysts and the International Monetary Fund are expecting, in an extreme situation, one of the three may have to be given up, and it should be the liberal capital account — in other words, resorting to capital controls particularly on portfolio inflows. This is the least costly measure in terms of growth and investment as there is no empirical evidence suggesting that a liberal capital account helps growth. Nobel laureate Andrew Michael Spence said as much during his recent visit to India: “You need to have capital controls and exchange rate management so that you have some control over the volatility of the prices that determine the way you interact with the rest of the world.”

Disclaimer: These are personal views of the writer. They do not necessarily reflect the opinion of www.business-standard.com or the Business Standard newspaper

Don't miss the most important news and views of the day. Get them on our Telegram channel

First Published: May 03 2010 | 12:54 AM IST

Explore News