POLITICAL ORDER AND POLITICAL DECAY
From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy
Francis Fukuyama
Straus & Giroux; 658 pages; $35
Also Read
Mr Fukuyama began the first volume, The Origins of Political Order, in 2011, by stating that the challenge for contemporary developing countries was how to "get to Denmark" - that is, how to build prosperous, well-governed, liberal democracies. This, in turn, required understanding what liberal democracy actually involved. Drawing on the insights of his mentor Samuel Huntington, Mr Fukuyama argued that political order was all about institutions, and that liberal democracy in particular rested on a delicate balance of three distinct features - political accountability; a strong, effective state; and the rule of law.
Mr Fukuyama showed how throughout history these three factors had often emerged independently or in various combinations. China, for example, developed a state long before any existed in Europe, yet did not acquire either the rule of law or political accountability. India and much of the Muslim world, by contrast, developed something like the rule of law early on, but not strong states (or, in much of the Muslim world, political accountability). It was only in parts of Europe in the late 18th century, Mr Fukuyama noted, that all three aspects started to come together simultaneously.
Political Order and Political Decay picks up the story at this point, taking the reader on a whirlwind tour of modern development from the French Revolution to the present. Mr Fukuyama is nothing if not ambitious. He wants to discover how and why liberal democracy develops.
Thus, he suggests that military competition can push states to modernise, citing ancient China and, more recently, Japan and Prussia. But he also notes many cases where military competition had no positive effect on state building (19th century Latin America) and many where it had a negative effect (Papua New Guinea, as well as other parts of Melanesia). And he suggests that the sequencing of political development is important, arguing that "those countries in which democracy preceded modern state building have had much greater problems achieving high-quality governance than those that inherited modern states from absolutist times". But the cases he gives as examples do not necessarily fit the argument well (since Prussia's state eventually had trouble deferring to civilian authorities and the early weakness of the Italian state was probably caused more by a lack of democracy than a surfeit of it).
Perhaps Mr Fukuyama's most interesting section is his discussion of the United States, which is used to illustrate the interaction of democracy and state building. Up through the 19th century, he notes, the United States had a weak, corrupt and patrimonial state. From the end of the 19th to the middle of the 20th century, however, the American state was transformed into a strong and effective independent actor, first by the Progressives and then by the New Deal. This change was driven by "a social revolution brought about by industrialization, which mobilized a host of new political actors with no interest in the old clientelist system".
Yet if the United States illustrates how democratic states can develop, it also illustrates how they can decline. Drawing on Huntington again, Mr Fukuyama reminds us that "all political systems - past and present - are liable to decay", as older institutional structures fail to evolve to meet the needs of a changing world.
Over the past few decades, American political development has gone into reverse, Mr Fukuyama says, as its state has become weaker, less efficient and more corrupt. One cause is growing economic inequality and concentration of wealth, which has allowed elites to purchase immense political power and manipulate the system to further their own interests. Another cause is the permeability of American political institutions to interest groups, allowing an array of factions that "are collectively unrepresentative of the public as a whole" to exercise disproportionate influence on government.
Mr Fukuyama fears that America's problems may increasingly come to characterise other liberal democracies.
His readers are, thus, left with a depressing paradox. Liberal democracy remains the best system for dealing with the challenges of modernity, and there is little reason to believe that Chinese, Russian or Islamist alternatives can provide the diverse range of economic, social and political goods that all humans crave. But unless liberal democracies can somehow manage to reform themselves and combat institutional decay, history will end not with a bang but with a resounding whimper.